Peer reviewed analysis from world leading experts

China's growing pains, globalisation and adjustment

Reading Time: 6 mins

In Brief

The fall of the Berlin wall in 1989 marked a new era of globalisation. Unlike previous eras, the surge of free trade and openness is characterised by an all encompassing division of labour, extending even into traditionally non-tradable services. The global system requires each country to position itself in the international value chain.

The most phenomenal feature of this global era is the economic ascent of China. Although China's per-capita income is only one twelfth of the United States', the rise of China is already sending shock waves throughout the world.

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Now the second largest economy in the world, China will overtake the US by 2025 at the latest. [1]

The world is feeling the pressures of China’s rapid development and economic might. Chinese exports are sold worldwide, often in established markets. With a growing hunger for resources, China has become the world’s second largest oil importer and the largest greenhouse gas emitter.

China is on the quest for a better life and has begun to coordinate international diplomatic efforts along with India, Brazil and South Africa; demonstrated most recently at the Copenhagen climate conference.

As the developing world asserts itself on the global market, the rest of the world feels the pain. Developed countries are losing traditional manufacturing jobs, and are forced to upgrade to higher value-added activities, especially financial services.

Specialisation has created so-called ‘global imbalances‘; some countries run high current account surpluses while other countries run high current account deficits and with one of the consequences being excessive liquidity flowing between them. Many attribute this to the recent financial crisis.

On the deficit side, the US, UK and Australia have adopted the Anglo-Saxon model of capitalism and maintain strong financial sectors. The surplus side is more diverse, comprised of the old manufacturing giants, namely, Germany and Japan; the newly emerged ‘world factories’, especially China; and oil exporters.

Here the key to understanding  the imbalances is to think about financial services as a tradable good. Traditional economic theory does not recognise them as such, thus it cannot be used to explain current account imbalances. This is because a surplus country experiencing an increase in wealth would import more until its current account surplus is depleted. Meanwhile, a deficit country faced with high interest rates would cut borrowings in order to rebalance its current account.

Treating financial services as a tradable good, it becomes easier to explain global imbalances. It is not a coincidence that the surplus countries do not have highly developed financial markets. They generally specialise in either manufacturing or in oil exporting. Finance is concentrated in places where efficiency is maximised, namely New York and London. It is no coincidence that the surplus countries have undeveloped financial markets that here ‘money’ is the input of the financial companies in New York and London, just like raw materials bought by any manufacturing company.

Financial markets in the surplus countries cannot channel income towards domestic investment or consumption. Ironically, the American financial market is often blamed entirely for causing the global financial crisis; although the American financial market may be too fluid, financial markets in the surplus countries are too static.

The financial crisis demonstrates the unsustainability of the current pattern of global specialisation. Yet the key issue is not sustainability, but adjustment.

Firstly, painful adjustment is required with the concentration of manufacturing in a few countries. Most developed countries need to create new job opportunities for their citizens..

Secondly, finance is increasingly concentrated in the hands of a few. In America wealth is concentrated in the top 0.1 per cent of the population. Global specialisation has led to what economists call ‘skill-biased’ technological change, which benefits the financial sector disproportionally. Large wage gaps should equalise with international trade according to the factor price equalisation theorem. Developed economies either have to adjust their wage rates down or endure unemployment if enough high-pay jobs cannot be created.

Initially, downward wage adjustment seems unavoidable. Yet, this translates into quality of life deterioration, which partially explains the developed world’s protectionist mood.

The challenge is equivalently severe in poor countries that face. the ‘trade trap’ and are forced to concentrate on exporting resource-based products.

Today, the late comers in Africa and South and Southeast Asia do not have the opportunity to accumulate domestic manufacturing capabilities in a protected environment. Even the emerging manufacturing economies are forced to rethink their growth models with environmental problems, inflationary pressures, and sluggish domestic demand. China’s heavy reliance on manufacturing has led to both internal and external imbalances. The phenomenal growth has not improved ordinary people’s lives.[2]

China’s large current account surpluses are invested in developed countries with only low returns. To maintain a fixed exchange rate against the dollar, the central bank must accumulate large dollar reserves, leading to constant inflationary pressure. Most Chinese economists agree that serious structural adjustments are needed to correct these imbalances. Increasing domestic demand is at the core of this adjustment process.

Global imbalances are commonly blamed on the surplus countries’ inflexible exchange rate regimes. Some point to China’s inflexible exchange rate regime as the root cause of unemployment in developed countries and the slow recovery in developing countries (see Krugman and Subramanian). However, historical evidence shows that exchange rate regimes are not associated with global imbalances. Germany and Japan both have a floating regime whilst maintaining very large surpluses. Furthermore, China’s trade and current account surpluses surged despite the 20 per cent appreciation in the Renimbi between 2005 and 2008.

Even if China’s adoption of a flexible exchange rate regime slightly helped the rest of the world in the short-term, China’s role has been exaggerated. In the end, economic fundamentals will dictate the game. Unless we reject free trade, the free flow of capital and division of labour, then we will have to live with global imbalances for a time. The problem is not how we correct the imbalances, but how we neutralise the negative consequences. No country alone can accomplish this task; global solutions must be sought.

One solution is to create non-country-specific financial assets that are sufficiently profitable to encourage investment from surplus countries. The IMF’s Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) could be such an asset. Most of the world remains very poor and desperately needs investment. Surplus countries will readily contribute if investments in developing countries are ensured to be profitable. Enlarging and strengthening the IMF and the World Bank would provide assistance. The recent round of the IMF’s recapitalisation and current efforts to create a regional fund in Asia is a good start.

Non-country-specific assets have two advantages; excessive liquidity will be re-channeled to invest in the real economy, reducing the risk of another financial crisis; and developing countries, receiving investment, will be able to improve their manufacturing capacities. China’s involvement in infrastructure building and direct investment in Africa should be welcomed. However, engagement is required by international development agencies. This requires a new international architecture for adjustment.

For a longer version of this article please see here.

Yang Yao is professor and director of the China Center for Economic Research (CCER), Peking University.


[1] The calculation makes the following assumptions: China grows by 7 per cent per annum and United States grows by 2 per cent per annum, both in real term; China’s inflation rate is 5.9 per cent and the US’s inflation rate is 3.5 per cent, the averages for the period 1981-2008; and RMB appreciates by 2 per cent per annum against the US dollar. If inflation and RMB appreciation are not considered, then China will take over the United States in 2032.

[2] Bai, Chong-En and Qian, Zhenjie. “Who Is Squeezing Residential Income?” Chinese Social Sciences, 2009, No. 5: 22-34.

3 responses to “China’s growing pains, globalisation and adjustment”

  1. There is clearly a need for more international assets classes for investors including sovereign funds and central banks.

    In that context, IMS SDR might be a good candidate. Alternatively, the World Bank could issue WB bonds. But for liquidity purposes, the IMF or the World Bank must be ready to act as a market maker too in case there is not enough liquidity.

    Leaving that aside, why can’t China be more innovative to set up an international bank to provide loans in foreign currencies at reasonably favourable rates to sovereign countries? In that way it can also have security and reasonable returns for its international reserves.

    Alternatively, why doesn’t China work together with the IMF or the World Bank to create some monetary facilities to create some new international financial asset classes.

    Once the issues of assets in foreign currencies and current account trade needs are separated, it is easier for China and indeed other countries too to move more freely on exchange rate issues.

  2. In addition to having more international financial assets for financing world development, I have some comments on a number of specific points in Yao’s article.

    While people often argue this or that and make statements on this or that, it is also fairly often that many arguments are incorrect even though they may be seemingly attractive to some particular audiences.

    It is said that “the financial crisis demonstrates the unsustainability of the current pattern of global specialisation.”

    But is that statement true or false? I would argue that it is not true but false. There are a number of reasons for my argument. Firstly, there is an issue on the real and fundamental cause of the financial crisis. While some people conveniently say it was the imbalances, most informed and rational people would think it was the malpractice lending by US banks associated with the sub-prime mortgages in the US prior to the crisis.

    Then was the malpractice a necessary product of the imbalances, that is, low costs of finance prevailing in the US back then? The answer again is negative and no. It was irresponsibility and greed by some banks. It was their mistakes. It had very little to do with low costs finance available. Who on the earth wants to unnecessarily raise the costs of finance, given that the US also needed and still in need of investment in infrastructure projects? Alternatively they could have used low costs financing to investment overseas in other countries. There was nothing inevitable for that malpractice to happen.

    Secondly, what is the problem with the current pattern of global specialisation? I can hardly see any and I think most people would not think it is a problem. Leaving the current practical and political issues aside, there are two points to argue for the positive of current global specialisation. One is that imbalances, whether it is domestic or international, households or regions or countries, are not necessarily a problem per se, as long as inter-temporal budget constraints are satisfied. It will be very counterproductive and welfare reducing one requires balance all the time for any unit. Why do people ignore this point when talking about imbalances just as if they are inherently a sin. They are not and are part of daily life and are good for everyone as long as they are responsible in their behaviour.

    Leaving that aside, it should be abundantly clear that there are mechanisms that can resolve or reduce imbalances should that really be a problem without the need to significantly alter the global specialisation pattern.

    I didn’t realise it is already so long in this comment, so I’d better take a rest on the case now.

  3. Since the IMF is controlled by the United States, it’s pretty much impossible that SDR’s will be designed to co-opt dollar hegemony, as the article suggests.

    Currency suppression is a conduit to wage suppression in export industries. Certainly Germany has enacted policies of wage suppression since the advent of the Euro, leading to the current Euro crisis. They have not used a currency peg , but that’s not the point. China has used the yuan peg as one instrument of wage suppression in its export industries.

    Capitalism has proven that it needs global regulator – which is the US. However this role is bankrupting the US both in terms of military expenditures and imbalances related to the Triffin dilemma.

    Capitalism without a global regulator is a scary world and that is where we are headed as long as private capital interests remain sacrosanct.

Support Quality Analysis

Donate
The East Asia Forum office is based in Australia and EAF acknowledges the First Peoples of this land — in Canberra the Ngunnawal and Ngambri people — and recognises their continuous connection to culture, community and Country.

Article printed from East Asia Forum (https://www.eastasiaforum.org)

Copyright ©2024 East Asia Forum. All rights reserved.