Peer reviewed analysis from world leading experts

Why exchange rate changes will not correct global trade imbalances

Reading Time: 9 mins

In Brief

Nobody disputes that almost three decades of US trade (net saving) deficits have made the global system of finance and trade more accident-prone. Outstanding dollar debts have become huge, and threaten America’s own financial future. Insofar as the principal creditor countries in Asia (Japan in the 1980s and 1990s, China since 2000) are industrial countries relying heavily on exports of manufactures, the transfer of their surplus savings to the saving-deficient US requires that they collectively run large trade surpluses in manufactures. The resulting large American trade deficits have worsened the ‘natural’ decline in the relative size of the American manufacturing sector, and eroded the US industrial base.

One unfortunate consequence of this industrial decline has been an outbreak of protectionism in the United States, which is exacerbated by the conviction that foreigners have somehow been cheating with their exchange rate and other commercial policies.

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

The most prominent of these have been associated with New York’s Senator Charles Schumer. In March 2005, he co-sponsored a bill to impose a 27.5 per cent tariff on all US imports from China until the RMB was appreciated. His bill was withdrawn in October 2006, when shown to be obviously incompatible with America’s obligations under the World Trade Organization. But Schumer threatens to craft a new China bill for 2010 that is WTO compatible.

Furthermore, Congressional legislation requires the Secretary of the Treasury to investigate any country that runs a trade surplus with the United States and to pronounce on whether or not the surplus country is manipulating its exchange rate. So far in 2010, the current Secretary— Timothy Geithner— has narrowly avoided having to label China a ‘currency manipulator’, which would involve as yet unspecified sanctions that could lead to a trade war.

However, the prevailing idea that a country’s exchange rate could, and indeed should, be used to bring its external trade into better balance is often wrong. Unfortunately, this conventional wisdom is based on faulty economic theorising. It need not apply in a globalised financial system where capital flows freely internationally. Under financial globalisation, forcing a creditor country such as China to appreciate its currency is neither necessary nor sufficient—and need not be even helpful—for reducing its trade surplus.  What are the issues involved?

 

The exchange rate and the trade balance: The debate

For a ‘home’ country, consider the identity from the national income accounts:

X – M = S – I = Trade (Saving) Surplus

where X is exports and M is imports (both broadly defined), and S is gross national saving and I is gross domestic investment

Most economists and commentators focus just on the left-hand side of this accounting identity.  It suggests that a depreciation of the home currency will make exports cheaper in world markets, and they will expand. Similarly, the home country’s imports will become more expensive in domestic currency, so they should contract. Thus conventional wisdom has it that the overall trade balance should improve if the underlying price elasticities for exporting and importing are even moderately high. This seemingly plausible result is very intuitive, so even journalists can understand and perpetuate it.

But this elasticities approach is basically microeconomic and quite deceptive. The export function X is looked at on its own, and the demand for imports M is looked at on its own, even by supposedly sophisticated econometricians who purport to measure separately the price elasticities of exports, and of imports, to exchange rate changes. Thus it is called the elasticities approach to the trade balance.

However, if you analyse the right-hand side (S – I) of the identity, the emphasis is macroeconomic. For the trade balance to improve with exchange depreciation, overall domestic expenditures must fall relative to aggregate output. This is the same as saying that domestic saving must rise relative to domestic investment. Looked at this way, one cannot presume that US net saving will rise when the dollar is devalued.

Indeed, the presumption may go the other way when domestic investment (fuelled in part by multinational firms) is sensitive to the exchange rate. Suppose the RMB were to appreciate sharply against the dollar. Potential investors, either foreign or domestic, would now see China as a more expensive place in which to invest and the US less expensive. This might set off a minor investment boom in the US, where investment expenditures rise from a relatively small base, and a major slump in China’s huge investment sector— which is currently about 45 per cent of GNP. Overall, investment-led expenditures in China would fall, the economy would contract, and Chinese imports could fall.

This is what happened to Japan from the 1980s into the mid-1990s when the yen went ever higher. Japan became a more costly place in which to invest, so that large Japanese firms decamped to invest in lower cost Asian countries, and in the US itself. Even though the yen appreciation slowed Japan’s export growth, the trade surplus of the slumping economy increased.

No wonder China is reluctant to appreciate! Like Japan in the 1980s and 90s, its trade (saving) surplus would likely not diminish because domestic saving is relatively insensitive to the exchange rate even though investment in a globalised financial-industrial world is sensitive.  However, foreign critics in the US and Europe with the misleading elasticities model (which doesn’t take international investment choices into account) in their heads, would come back and say ‘you just didn’t appreciate enough’. With this adverse expectation of continual RMB appreciation, the upshot would be further hot money inflows. The People’s Bank of China would be, as it has been, forced to intervene to buy dollars on a grand scale to prevent an indefinite upward spiral in the RMB. But the accumulation of dollar foreign exchange reserves threatens a loss of internal monetary control as base money in China’s banking system expands at an equal rate, and somehow has to be sterilised.

Currency Mismatches and the Impossibility of a Free Yuan/Dollar Float

 

While a discrete appreciation of the RMB— by moving the government- controlled peg for the yuan/ dollar rate—would be deleterious, isn’t there an alternative market-based solution for determining the exchange rate?

While visiting Boeing and other exporters in Washington State Geithner said ‘It is China’s decision about what to do with the exchange rate – they’re a sovereign country.’ Adding, ‘But I think it is enormously in their interest to move, over time, to let the exchange rate reflect market forces, and I am confident that they will do what is in their interest.’

Secretary Timothy Geithner’s tone here is much more measured and careful than in previous episodes of American China bashing where various congressmen, journalists, industrialists, union officials, and economists— intellectually trapped by the elasticities model— have called for a large appreciation of the RMB against the dollar. But would Secretary Geithner’s more moderate and seemingly reasonable approach to let the yuan/dollar rate reflect ‘market forces’ (i.e. by floating) work?

China has a large ongoing net saving (trade) surplus that somehow has to be financed by lending to foreigners. But the RMB is not (yet) an internationally accepted currency.  Thus the buildup of financial claims on foreigners is largely denominated in dollars, not RMB. Moreover, with the threat that the RMB might appreciate in the future, foreigners become even more loath to borrow in RMB.  So we have the making of a severe currency mismatch if the People’s Bank of China (PBC) were to withdraw from the foreign exchange market, i.e. stop buying the dollars necessary to stabilise the yuan/dollar rate.

Under such a free float, Chinese private (nonstate) financial institutions such as banks, insurance companies, and pension funds, would become responsible for financing the trade surplus. So they would have to build up dollar claims on the asset side of their balance sheets even though their liabilities—domestic bank deposits, annuity and pension obligations— were denominated in RMB. Because of this mismatch, they would face the threat of bankruptcy should the dollar depreciate.

China’s current account surpluses have been so large, between $200 billion and $300 billion per year, that when cumulated would quickly dwarf the net worth of China’s private financial institutions.  Thus, except for transitory transacting, these private institutions would refuse to accumulate the dollar claims being thrown off by the current account surplus once the PBC left the market.  Under such a free float with no willing buyers of dollars, the RMB would just spiral upward indefinitely with no well-defined upper bound for its dollar exchange rate.  (And remember that the appreciated RMB need not reduce China’s trade surplus)

Of course the PBC could not just stand idly while a continually appreciating RMB caused both exports and domestic investment to slump. So it would revoke its free float and re-enter the foreign exchange market to buy dollars to re-stabilise the yuan/dollar rate. But this adventure in floating would have further undermined expectations, and make it more difficult to re-establish a credible yuan/dollar rate from which hot money inflows were absent. The PBC and State Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE) could well find themselves with much larger dollar exchange reserves than the current incredibly high US$2.5 trillion, and with the economy knocked off its high growth path.

What is the more general lesson here? Suppose a creditor country continues with high net saving (S – I) leading to a large buildup of foreign currency claims. The resulting currency mismatch within its domestic financial system will cause a free float to break down. Unlike what Secretary Geithner suggests, there is no market solution. So the best that the country can do is to stabilise its exchange rate through official intervention sufficiently credibly so that hot money flows are minimised.  And this is the strategy that China has been trying to follow, but is continually knocked off course by American and European ‘China bashing’ to appreciate the RMB.

The Way Out

 

In the short term (and possibly forever), foreigners should stop bashing China on the exchange rate. A credibly stable exchange rate would eliminate hot money inflows into China and make it much easier for the PBC to continue with its huge domestic credit expansion, which has made China the leading force in global economic recovery.

In the medium term, better balance net saving in the US and China.  The US should cut back on its huge fiscal deficits and constrain private consumption while China continues stimulating private consumption. With trade better balanced, American manufacturing could recover and protectionist pressures would lessen.

In the long term, China should continue to encourage the ‘internationalisation’ of the RMB. With a stable yuan/dollar rate, foreigners would be more willing to borrow in RMB from Chinese banks and even be willing to issue RMB-denominated bonds in Shanghai. By gradually escaping from its internal currency mismatch, China would be well on the road to becoming a ‘mature’ international creditor.

Ronald I. McKinnon is the William D. Eberle Professor of International Economics at Stanford University.

3 responses to “Why exchange rate changes will not correct global trade imbalances”

  1. Dear Prof McKinnon,

    Thank you for this concise analysis.

    I have always agreed with the headline of this piece.
    I can now explain the reasoning to students in a rather more sophisticated way.

    Best wishes,

    Andrew Elek

  2. I have to take issue with the characterisation of ‘protectionism’ that is put forward in this article – the examples cited do not constitute ‘protectionism’ but are examples of protectionist rhetoric – quite a different thing altogether.

    If there was a concerted effort at ‘protectionism’, then Schumer’s legislation would have been passed – it didn’t and was no doubt pulled because it didn’t have sufficient support. Moreover, where has the recent letter by 100 or so Congressmen gone? Geithner has fudged the decision of ‘currency manipulation’.

    In addition, ‘protectionism’ is portrayed as something of a pejorative in this piece. I appreciate that economists in the main like to cite the mantra that trade is good and increases all countries GDP and that protectionism is bad, with oft-cited example of the inter-war years but such mantras often obscure the details of who actually benefits from these situations. This is not to say that I am defending ‘protectionism’ but rather that the author was more explicit in his own ideological bias. Indeed, this is the principal problem with the article – I enjoyed the detailed analysis and it puts forward a strong case for this particular course of action but it would be better served if it acknowledged its own bias. Rather, it hides behind the camouflage of “economics” but that’s a falsehood – all economics is inherently political because it involves making choices. The course of action in this article is presented as the best – but leaves out precisely who it is best for?

    This then comes back to the references to protectionism – US politicians aren’t motivated by taking the best course of action for the global economy – economics may be global in nature but politics is still local. Their electorates are not in China. Hence, they are motivated by taking decisions that are seen to lessen the pain of US workers. Indeed, this whole aspect of the currency debate is curiously absent from this article. Curious because I would argue that the inter-related issues of workers’ wages, job losses and US companies’ outsourcing are really driving the debate on China’s currency in the US.

    Moreover, in contrast to the characterisation of the economic logic presented here, I don’t know if people are solely focusing on the elasticities of trade. The article assumes that appreciating the currency will not affect savings rate and investment spending side of the equation. Maybe. But I have seen other economists argue that, by appreciating the currency, the cost of Chinese exports will increase and, if you accept the argument that cheap Chinese goods has contributed to increased consumption, then a rise in the value of these goods could increase the savings rate and so more balanced trade could be achieved this way.

    Personally, I don’t think it is clear that this would happen (capital could just relocate to other sites to negate the increased costs) and, if even it did, it may not offset the increase in investment. I just find it strange that such a scenario was omitted from the article while the increase in investment was outlined. It all just creates a sense of perpetuating a particular viewpoint without being explicit about where it is coming from.

  3. It appears that there are more than one factor working in the issues of trade balances – the elasticity and more fundamentally savings and investment behaviours, as well as various preferences and behaviour inertias, both short and long terms.

    Economic reality is invariantly much more complex than many nice but mostly partial economic theories and models based on certain assumptions and focus on certain aspects of the reality.

    The main issues are largely empirical in nature.

    The US has tended to run trade deficits for fairly long period of time, with different countries on the other side of the balance from time to time and as its target of trade wars.

    The question is not just China with its currency pegged to the $US has trade surplus with the US, but also some other countries whose currencies are free to adjust that also have trade surpluses with the US.

    While the US can blame China for fixed exchange rate, how should it blame those other countries?

    Besides, bilateral trade balance is not and should not be the benchmark for trade balance in a multi-country trade in the world as it is. To require bilateral trade balance will mean huge losses in global welfare due to losses in trade opportunities.

    Further, optimal trade balance even for a country should be over a sufficiently long period and should not mean balance year by year.

    But trade is economic as well as political, so people from short term political point of view often selectively quote or use some partial economic theories to their advance their arguments. Even economists sometimes can act either inadvertently or deliberately in that way.

    Paul Krugman, a fairly recent Nobel Economics laureate, is an example in this regard.

    Of course, he is famous for strategic trade theories, after all.

Support Quality Analysis

Donate
The East Asia Forum office is based in Australia and EAF acknowledges the First Peoples of this land — in Canberra the Ngunnawal and Ngambri people — and recognises their continuous connection to culture, community and Country.

Article printed from East Asia Forum (https://www.eastasiaforum.org)

Copyright ©2024 East Asia Forum. All rights reserved.