Peer reviewed analysis from world leading experts

The turning period in Chinese development

Reading Time: 6 mins

In Brief

What are the implications of the turning period for China’s continuing economic development, for China’s interaction with the global economy and for economic policy? Here I focus on four of the most important consequences, mention a consequence that is widely anticipated and feared, but which need not eventuate, and briefly discuss one way in which perceptions of China’s growth will be affected by its having entered the turning period.

As China enters deeply into the turning period (when unlimited supplies of labour become more difficult to mobilise for industrial development), there will be large and continuing increases in real wages and in the wage share of income.

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

The powerful tendency since the 1980s towards increased inequality in income distribution is likely to be reversed. The rise in the wage share of income is likely to be reflected in an increase in the consumption share of expenditure. There will be a reduction in the national savings rate.

It is possible that the investment rate will in fact rise. Whether or not this is the case, it is likely that China’s savings rate will fall more than its investment rate. This will reduce the external surplus in trade and current payments. It will therefore ease current international pressures over payments imbalances and exchange rates. It would be wise for China to ensure that total domestic demand expands enough to ensure that this is the case.

The reduction in Chinese current external payments surpluses is therefore a second important consequence of moving through the turning period. This could ease tensions with other countries — especially the United States — which have identified Chinese surpluses as a principal cause of their own economic problems. Regrettably, a large fall in Chinese savings relative to investment would put upward pressure on global long-term interest rates and increase the requirement to reduce domestic expenditure on goods and services in the countries facing large challenges in the management of external and public debt, including the United States.

The third important consequence of China moving through and beyond the turning period is that the centre of China’s comparative advantage in international trade will shift rapidly from a fairly narrow range of labour-intensive products to a wider range of more capital-intensive and technologically sophisticated products. This will ease some dimensions of China’s trade problems with the rest of the world (perceptions of competitive pressure on other developing countries and heavily concentrated pressures for adjustment on particular sectors in industrialised countries) and complicate others (competitive pressures will be felt across a much wider range of industries in industrialised countries). The diversification of China’s comparative advantage will probably halt the decline in Chinese export prices that was associated with the heavy concentration of export expansion in a small number of products.

The fourth important consequence of entering the turning period involves a policy risk to economic stability and growth in the period ahead. Rising real wages and the pressure of strong increases in demand for non-traded goods and services will be inflationary unless accompanied by a combination of firm monetary policy and an appreciating renminbi. Nevertheless, the Chinese authorities might be tempted to maintain the fixed exchange rate against the US dollar to avoid adjustment pressures on export-oriented labour-intensive industries, which have played such an important part in Chinese economic growth since the mid 1980s.

To seek to maintain a fixed exchange rate against the US dollar through and beyond the turning period would only postpone and not avoid the structural adjustments that are a necessary accompaniment of the current stage of Chinese economic growth. Payments surpluses would eventually overwhelm the efforts to sterilise their monetary effects. The adjustments would occur through inflation.

It is likely that the authorities would respond to higher inflation by tightening fiscal and monetary policies. This would unnecessarily reduce the rate of economic growth below sustainable levels and postpone the increase in Chinese living standards that can come through and beyond the turning period. The inflation and the delays in inequality reductions could be destabilising to domestic political stability. The delays in reduction in the external payments surplus would certainly be destabilising for China’s productive interaction with the international economy and society.

There is one consequence of moving through and beyond the turning period that is often feared but which is unlikely to be important unless there are mistakes in economic policy, and one important implication for perceptions of the growth of the Chinese economy. There is no basis for the expectation that China’s rate of growth in output per worker must necessarily fall as it moves through and beyond the turning period. The rise in real wages as China moves through the turning period is likely to lead to an increase in the rate of total factor productivity growth. In the nature of things, this will be concentrated in industries producing relatively sophisticated and capital-intensive products, the competitiveness of which is less sensitive to increases in real wages. It is possible that the increase in Chinese domestic demand that is necessary to reduce external current payments surpluses will require an increase in the investment rate for a while. Together with the expected acceleration of productivity growth, this would support an increase in the growth rate in total output per worker, above the high rates of the early twenty-first century. That could surprise the world and also the Chinese authorities, but it may well be necessary to maintain internal and external balance in the period ahead.

How successful China is economically in this period of rapidly rising real wages will depend on the flexibility of the economy, its openness to foreign trade and investment and the world’s most productive ideas about managing enterprises, the quality of the human resources created by the rapid expansion of the education system in the past couple of decades and the quality of the regulatory systems applied to the more complex economy that is emerging. It is possible that the rate of growth in total output can be maintained at something like the average rates of the decades of reform, until the approach of the industrialised countries’ frontiers of productivity and living standards reduces the scope of rapid productivity growth through ‘catching up’ with the industrialised countries.

Whether or not China succeeds in maintaining such high aggregate rates of growth until it reaches the frontiers of the world economy, most observers will be surprised by how quickly China catches up now that it has entered the turning period. China’s real exchange rate will rise rapidly — whether that occurs through inflation, nominal exchange rate appreciation or a combination of the two. The value of China’s output when measured in the national accounts and converted into international currency at current exchange rates will converge towards the much higher ‘purchasing power’ estimates of GDP. People in China and abroad who focus on conventional measures of national output will find that China catches up with the world’s most productive economies in output per person — and with the United States in total output — much more quickly than they had been expecting from extrapolation of differentials in national growth rates.

Ross Garnaut  is Vice-Chancellor’s Fellow and Professorial Fellow in Economics at the University of Melbourne. He is also Distinguished Professor of Economics at the Australian National University. This essay is an excerpt from Chapter 2 in ‘China: The Next 20 Years of Reform and Development,’ Ross Garnaut, Jane Golley and Ligang Song (eds). For Professor Garnaut’s background notes and recent papers see www.rossgarnaut.com.au.

Ross Garnaut’s full chapter from this year’s China Update, China: The Next Twenty Years of Reform and Development, can be downloaded from here.

2 responses to “The turning period in Chinese development”

  1. Interesting piece as always from this excellent forum. The only query I have is with the notion that China has now entered the ‘turning period’. The latest data may contradict me given the numerous news reports about strikes and wage hikes, but from what I can gather productivity growth is still much faster than wage growth (though the gap is narrowing). Meanwhile there is still a vast amount of workers employed in agriculture. My understanding is that until wages begin growing faster than productivity, then inflation won’t be a major problem and the present macro approach.

  2. Excellent analysis and insight into China’s next phase of economic development.

    The impact of diminishing labour surplus and the consequential rise in wages are likely to be complex and will require very prudent management of both macro and micro economic issues. The rise in raw material and energy costs will further erode China’s international competitiveness.

    While currency appreciation may offset some of the pressures of inflation due to constraints from labour supply, it would further exacerbate the loss in its international competitiveness associated with supply side issues. It could lead to significant slowdown due to a potential double whamming effect, if currency appreciation is excessive.

    Adding to that is that further real urbanisation is likely to expand domestic demand not only from housing and urban infrastructure, but also general consumption.

    A prudent course is likely to be:

    1. Focuse on structural change and raising labour productivity to compensate the rise in labour costs, by investing in more capital intensive technologies, industries and products, using the currency surplus as a temporary buffer for adjustments

    2. Adjust the exchange rate at appropriate time when productivity transformation is showing dividends in international competitiveness and well entrenched

    3. Further focus on sustained expansion of domestic demand

    From micro point of view, labour market reforms to reduce discriminations and better reflect productivity, reforming capital market to increase the efficiency of capital allocation especially accessibility to capital by the private sector including small and medium sized firms, reduce monopolies by increasing effective competition and barriers to entry, reduce transition costs for industries and firms by deregulation especially government red tapes and barriers (including local government’s land management), as well facilitating industry adjustment to raise labour productivity.

    However, one factor may facilitate this productivity transformation process is the currently under employment of its higher education graduates. Those would become one of the key factors in upgrading the skills of its labour forces.

    Nevertheless, the adjustments will be a very complex and difficult process that must be accompanied with prudent management.

Support Quality Analysis

Donate
The East Asia Forum office is based in Australia and EAF acknowledges the First Peoples of this land — in Canberra the Ngunnawal and Ngambri people — and recognises their continuous connection to culture, community and Country.

Article printed from East Asia Forum (https://www.eastasiaforum.org)

Copyright ©2024 East Asia Forum. All rights reserved.