Peer reviewed analysis from world leading experts

Indonesia’s long road to economic stability

Reading Time: 4 mins
Indonesia moved to a floating exchange rate system in 1997 and has been targeting soft inflation since 2005. (Photo: AAP)

In Brief

Indonesia has come a long way since former president Suharto adopted a new economic stabilisation policy in 1996. But the country must take steps to improve infrastructure and enhance data measurement if it is to realise its economic potential.

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

During the 1960s, in the early years of Suharto’s regime, Indonesia’s budget deficit was financed by only long-term concessionary loans from the International Governmental Group on Indonesia — the official development source. Suharto called this the ‘balanced budget rule’. The budget and debt rules replaced the inflationary financing policies of the previous president Sukarno. And the policy change reduced inflation from over 650 per cent in 1966 down to 10 per cent in 1969. This in turn enabled the government to start implementing the First Five Year Development Plan on 1 April 1969.

President Suharto’s administration repressed the banking system by setting detailed ceilings on bank credit and forcing interest rates down — sometimes below inflation rates. It allocated credit by prioritising economic sectors, certain classes of customers and individual credit recipients. Bank governance was bad with widespread corruption, collusion and nepotism. The central bank provided the liquidity credit to finance credit programs while credit risks were assumed by the state-owned credit insurance company.

Before the Asian Financial Crisis in 1997, Indonesia had a fixed exchange rate system. Bank Indonesia (BI) had full control of the domestic and foreign components of the monetary base. It controlled the former through lending to commercial banks and the latter through buying and selling units of foreign exchange at fixed prices in exchange for domestic money. To keep the monetary base unchanged, BI credited the surplus in foreign exchange as reserves. It also countered the devaluing effects of foreign exchange reserves on the monetary base through sterilising surpluses. It sold its own certificates and other securities to banks in order to absorb the increasing reserves.

Indonesia moved to a floating exchange rate system in 1997, meaning BI lost control of monetary authority on the foreign component of the monetary base. It shifted its goal to inflation targeting and began using the one-month bond certificate interest rate as the operating target of monetary policy. In 2000, Indonesia began targeting soft inflation and since 2005 has adopted the Taylor-type rule — the central bank increases the nominal interest rate by more than one percentage point after a one per cent increase in inflation. Inflation targeting is supported by the new fiscal and debt rules. The budget deficit is limited to 3 per cent of GDP and the debt-to-GDP ratio must remain below 60 per cent.

On 9 July 2008, BI changed the operational target from the one-month certificate interest rate to the overnight interbank interest rate.

In general, central banks set a neutral real interest rate if monetary policy is neither expansionary nor contractionary. The neutral or equilibrium interest rate depicts stable inflation and a zero output gap (with the economy running at full potential) over the medium term. The central bank sets the real interest rate above the neutral rate to dampen economic growth. The difference between actual policy rate and the neutral real interest rate is called the interest rate gap, which can be used to evaluate the monetary policy stance needed to close the output gap.

But it is not clear whether BI’s estimated long-run equilibrium natural interest rate in Indonesia should be similar to that of the US. Like the US, the coefficient for the inflation gap is nearly two and the output gap is 0.25. The potential output estimate is based on the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, which links real growth with changes in employment, financial markets, capital stocks, CPI inflation and capacity utilisation. These data are limited or unavailable in Indonesia.

The results are further complicated by fragmented input and products markets. A combination of geography, weak and high-cost interregional transportation, and distorted government policies cause this fragmentation. And this means Indonesia is yet to exploit its large geography and population. It is still a dual economy with a substantial low-productivity informal sector. In a small open economy like Indonesia, the exchange rate affects both the interest rate and core inflation and CPI through the pass through effect. These issues must be addressed before Indonesia can properly close the output gap.

Anwar Nasution is Emeritus Professor of Economics at the University of Indonesia, Jakarta. This article is a digest of the author’s chapter in the recent book Macroeconomic Policies in Indonesia: Indonesian economy since the Asian financial crisis in 1997 (Routledge, 2015).

Comments are closed.

Support Quality Analysis

Donate
The East Asia Forum office is based in Australia and EAF acknowledges the First Peoples of this land — in Canberra the Ngunnawal and Ngambri people — and recognises their continuous connection to culture, community and Country.

Article printed from East Asia Forum (https://www.eastasiaforum.org)

Copyright ©2024 East Asia Forum. All rights reserved.