Peer reviewed analysis from world leading experts

Chinese industry: a tale of two sectors

Reading Time: 5 mins
A Sinopec petrol station in China, August 2015. (Photo: David Hall, Flickr).

In Brief

China’s state monopolies survive alongside a cut-throat private sector.

The recent announcement of China Minmetals merger with MCG and this year’s mergers of China North Rail with China South Rail have fuelled ongoing speculation about the further consolidation of China’s state sector.

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

These mega-mergers feed the perception that China is pursuing ‘state capitalism’ dominated by massive state monopolies. But other economists, emphasising the triumph of private markets, argue that the dominance of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) is a misconception. A close look at China’s industrial data shows that while manufacturing is private-sector led and highly competitive, resources and utilities are in state hands and much more likely to be concentrated.

A straight calculation of industry concentration — the conventional indicator for a potential monopoly — based on the latest available (2009) official survey of 420,000 enterprises in 521 industrial subsectors (not including finance or telecommunications), suggests that less than 3 per cent of industrial revenue accrues to potentially monopolised sectors. The largest concentrated sectors manufacture air conditioners, refrigerators and specialised equipment for electricity distribution. The most monopolised is a tiny industry that manufactures buoys. At first glance, this refutes the claim that China’s economy is dominated by monopoly SOEs.

But we shouldn’t accept the standard measure at face value. The official survey collects data for individual plants and factories, not entire corporate groups, which can be very large indeed. In 2009, 56 SOEs in the industrial sector controlled by the top-level State Owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC) had 10,442 first and second-tier subsidiaries. China’s three largest companies — in oil and electricity — are sprawling empires, not single firms, with subsidiaries in unrelated competitive sectors.

To find monopolies in the Chinese data, it’s first necessary to put these pieces together. This is a daunting task. Below the central SASAC, all Chinese provinces have their own state assets commissions that supervise at least another 25,000 local SOEs and subsidiaries. Instead of identifying a corporate group for each factory, a new approach assigns SOE revenue to either central SASAC (for central SOEs) or the relevant provincial SASAC (for local SOEs). For example, all SOE coal mines in Hebei province are treated as a single Hebei Coal SOE. And all central SOEs in oil extraction are assigned to a single Central Oil SOE. This effectively treats each SASAC as the parent company of mega-corporate groups.

Putting subsidiaries together in this way reveals a few, large, potentially concentrated sectors — notably oil, electricity and tobacco. These are all dominated by SOEs. Using this measure, almost a third of Chinese industrial revenue goes to concentrated sectors.

But there are still large state-owned sectors, namely steel and coal, in which industry concentration is very low. These are dominated by provincial SOEs. Other big manufacturing sectors, in textiles and electronics, have scarcely any state ownership. China’s least concentrated industry is apparel.

Four useful generalisations can be drawn from these statistics. Most Chinese industrial assets are in unconcentrated sectors and the competitive sectors of the Chinese economy are predominantly non-state owned. Provincial and local SOEs tend to hold assets in unconcentrated sectors, while the concentrated sectors of the Chinese economy are predominantly owned by central SOEs.

So do central SOEs convert their market concentration into massive monopoly profits?

Overall, average profit margins for the state and non-state sectors have been much the same since 2008. But a direct comparison between the state and private sectors is misleading, because non-state enterprise assets are almost entirely in manufacturing sectors. Central SOEs are different — 14 per cent of central SOE assets are in resources (mainly oil) and more than 40 per cent are in utilities (mainly electricity). High profit margins from the former compensate for wafer thin margins in the latter. And at both ends of the spectrum, prices are still determined by state policy, not driven by market competition. Deregulating prices remains a work in progress.

Where does this leave the debate between state capitalism and the role of the market?

Most ‘made in China’ consumer goods are made by private companies engaged in cut-throat competition. Dominant state monopolies only survive in a few key sectors, predominantly resources and utilities. But here it’s hard to disentangle ‘state capitalism’ from a policy choice to use ownership as a regulatory tool. This choice is common in developing, and even some developed, countries.

A private oil company is only a good policy alternative to a state oil company if there’s a very strong framework for taxing resource rents. Given the public goods nature of network utilities, it makes no sense to turn a public monopoly into a private one, unless the state is willing and able to enforce regulatory discipline. Some other sectors, for example weapons manufacturing or nuclear power, remain in state hands primarily for national security reasons. These policy choices aren’t unique to China, nor are they specifically ‘state capitalist’.

It’s precisely the political implications that make economic monopolies a vital issue for China. Monopoly conglomerates couple the opportunity to extract economic rents with the capacity to control a nationwide bureaucracy. The Communist Party of China has a monopoly over both.

Paul Hubbard is a Sir Roland Wilson PhD Scholar at the Crawford School of Public Policy, The Australian National University, a visiting scholar at the National School of Development, Peking University. He is on leave from the Australian Treasury. These are his personal views and do not reflect those of the Treasury.

This article is based on an EABER working paper.

 

5 responses to “Chinese industry: a tale of two sectors”

  1. In modern economies, the existence of monopoly companies, regardless they are public-owned or private-owned, does not translate to monopoly profits. Utility industries have more monopoly companies.
    For example, water supply in the ACT has been provided by Icon Water, part of the Actew Corporation. The price of water supply is determined by the Independent and Competition and Regulatory Commission, a statutory body.
    Further, Actew is owned by the ACT government.
    The author also stated that:
    “High profit margins from the former (oil industry) compensate for wafer thin margins in the latter (electricity). And at both ends of the spectrum, prices are still determined by state policy, not driven by market competition. Deregulating prices remains a work in progress.”
    What it says is that there may be distortions in those two sectors in that the price may not reflect accurately the costs. But it is a different matter that there are economic rents that the state is getting from its monopoly SOEs.
    So I find the following statement hard to understand:
    “Monopoly conglomerates couple the opportunity to extract economic rents with the capacity to control a nationwide bureaucracy.”

    • While the author did not seem to measure it, a more important issue is how efficient are the SOEs, given that many argue that they are less efficient.

  2. The total labor force of a country comprises of people who meet the International Labour Organization definition of the economically active population, ie, all people who supply labor for the production of goods and services during a specified period.

    It includes both the employed and the unemployed, the armed forces, and first-time job-seekers, but excludes homemakers and other unpaid caregivers.

    According to the World Bank, China’s workforce in 2014 totalled 806.5 million, which almost equaled the combined population of the US, Canada, Australia, NZ and Europe.

    No Government in the West has any experience to manage such a colossal workforce in the history of mankind.

    In an al jazeera piece dated 13 Sept 2015, entitled “China unveils details to fix state-owned enterprises”, it reported that China’s government manages 111 companies centrally under the State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission, or SASAC. Local governments own and manage around 25,000 state-owned companies and the sector employs nearly 7.5 million people.”

    If that is true then I like to know who employs the rest of the other nearly 800 million workers.

    In circa 1978, China’s Premier Deng Xiaoping declared that “it’s not the color of the cat that counts but whether it can catch mice.”

    With that guiding principle the Marxist ideology was thrown out of the window and China adopted Meritocracy and a market economy with a socialist administration.

    Today, after just 37 years, China has lifted over 900 million out of poverty. It is now the largest trading country in the world, the world’s second largest economy and has a foreign reserves of US$3.44 trillion.

    China must be doing something right.

    • I will give credit for the Chinese government for what they have done to their economy; however, they did get some major help from the American companies who shipped their manufacturing jobs overseas and were forced to do technology transfer as demand by the government.

  3. “It’s precisely the political implications that make economic monopolies a vital issue for China. Monopoly conglomerates couple the opportunity to extract economic rents with the capacity to control a nationwide bureaucracy. The Communist Party of China has a monopoly over both”.

    And why not? The Communist Party of China is the finest steward of public money the world has ever seen, as its results prove. If it extracts rents, then it applies those revenues to ensuring that, for example, 95% of poor Chinese own their homes free and clear and have free medical care and an income.

    And any government that lacks “the capacity to control a nationwide bureaucracy” is not a government at all.

Support Quality Analysis

Donate
The East Asia Forum office is based in Australia and EAF acknowledges the First Peoples of this land — in Canberra the Ngunnawal and Ngambri people — and recognises their continuous connection to culture, community and Country.

Article printed from East Asia Forum (https://www.eastasiaforum.org)

Copyright ©2024 East Asia Forum. All rights reserved.