Peer reviewed analysis from world leading experts

Can China lay its zombie firms to rest?

Reading Time: 5 mins

In Brief

2016 began with international media attention drawn to the weakness of China’s economy. This prediction was validated on 9 May 2016 when the People’s Daily ran on its front page an article written by President Xi Jinping that expounded on the need for ‘supply-side structural reform’.

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

One of the structural flaws driving China’s instability is the soft budget constraint — an investment situation where profits of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) are largely privatised to SOE personnel and losses of SOEs are socialised on to the state budget. This situation results in reckless investment by SOEs and a complacent willingness by state-owned banks to supply funds for the investments.

The re-emergence of pervasive soft budget behaviour with the 2008 macro-stimulus package is the cause of the large amount of excess capacity in China’s heavy industries today, and also of the serious but still-hidden non-performing loan (NPL) problem in state-owned banks. By early 2014, analysts had started warning about the worsening levels of excess capacity and the inevitable appearance of NPLs. As NPLs would be avoided if the SOEs could pay back the loan principal before debt-servicing difficulties appear, the government began encouraging the SOEs in 2014 to issue new shares and use the proceeds to pay back bank loans.

Simultaneously, the government started promoting the stock market to the general public as a good investment vehicle for savings. The result of this talking up of the stock market was that the stock market climbed steeply — a rise that was also helped by stock market manipulation by some large investment funds. The Shanghai Stock Market Index rose 150 per cent between June 2014 and June 2015. The dramatic boom ended badly in the form of an equally dramatic crash that began on 12 June 2015. The Shanghai Stock Market had lost one-third of its value by 12 July 2015.

The reason for the reversal of stock prices is obvious. What rate of return could an SOE pay on its equities when it could not afford to pay the interest on its bank loan? The rate of return on this SOE’s shares has to be lower than the average loan rate. This understanding would inevitably prevail and the stock bubble would then end.

The term ‘zombie firm’ was coined to describe a firm that continues to operate despite being unable to service its loans at the market interest rate. Zombie firms will show profits when they receive subsidies of various types — for example, concessionary interest rates on loans and bank debt being converted to equities held by the banks. As most of the firms with substantial excess capacity are zombie firms, it is common to use these two terms interchangeably. The growing presence of zombie firms since 2008 coincides with the downward trend in the growth of productivity — the ultimate engine of economic growth.

Two main ways have been proposed for solving the zombie firm problem and the excess capacity problem: demand-side measures and supply-side measures, with the more common names for them being macro-stimulus and structural reform, respectively.

The most direct demand-side measures to deal with excess capacity are to initiate projects that require the products of these zombie firms as inputs (for example, a railroad project to use more cement and steel), and to extend financial subsidies to maintain production and then put the output into inventory. Both of these macro-stimulus measure are sensible only if the rate of return equals (or exceeds) the interest rate; and these macro-stimulus measures are sustainable only if the rate of return is non-zero.

The most direct supply-side measure to deal with excess capacity are to shut down excess capacity, but this will create unemployment as it takes time for labour to be reallocated to other sectors. An alternative that is commonly proposed is to retool the factories to manufacture other goods. The problem with this is that most equipment in heavy industries are highly task-specific, making this suggestion infeasible.

In China’s case at present, these two competing ways of dealing with excess capacity present the choice between short-run stability and long-run stagnation on one hand and, on the other, below target growth in the short run and avoidance of the middle income trap in the long run. The fact is that the structural adjustment cannot be postponed indefinitely because the macro-stimulus cannot be sustained indefinitely. The longer the structural reform is put off, the more costly the structural adjustment when it inevitably happens.

My recent research gives another reason for why supply-side structural reform should be prioritised over demand-side. The stimulus of state-directed investments during the 2003–13 period crowded out private sector growth, while serving as a lifeline for economically inefficient zombie firms.

There are two conditions for supply-side structural reforms to be carried to completion. The economic condition is that the government must stop the practice of soft budget constraint by denying bank loans to zombie firms and changing the institutional incentive of mutual back-scratching between the government and the SOEs. The political condition for successful structural reforms is that adequate social safety nets and retraining programs for laid off workers must be implemented to reduce the social pain generated by economic restructuring.

The fundamental prerequisite for China in avoiding the middle income trap is good governance. The government must allow price signals from competitive markets to guide resource allocation and strengthen national innovation except in cases of well-known market failures; and must entrench social programs that ensure inclusive economic growth and accelerate upward social mobility.

Wing Thye Woo is President of the Jeffrey Cheah Institute on Southeast Asia at Sunway University, and Professor at University of California, Davis, Fudan University, and Chinese Academy of Social Sciences.

This article is a digest of the authors’ chapter from the publication for the latest China Update, which was held at the ANU on Friday 22 July. A free e-book is available here.

2 responses to “Can China lay its zombie firms to rest?”

  1. “Good governance” as part of supply side solutions will require that the government’s leaders help the population through the upheavals of job loss, etc. Can/will they do that?

    Or will they continue to focus its energies on its SCS and other nationalistic policies? The latter allow the government to distract its people from the underlying economic, social, and demographic challenges it faces.

  2. It would be interesting to see how transition to demand-side economics will unfold and will make many academic studies in years to come Shiro Armstrong and Tom Westland piece is contradictory to sustainable economic growth guided by meaningful labor reform rather it appears to advocate entrenchment of accumulation and supply side economics at the cost of labor this is in the face of 2008 crisis which laid to bare China’s economic fragility to changing trade factors.

    On a side not but equally important

    Will the CCP shift its rhetoric towards internal polices to highlight structural inefficiencies and match this with actions to reassure ordinary Chinese of a brighter future or will it continue the self defeating strongman geopolitical rhetoric.

Support Quality Analysis

Donate
The East Asia Forum office is based in Australia and EAF acknowledges the First Peoples of this land — in Canberra the Ngunnawal and Ngambri people — and recognises their continuous connection to culture, community and Country.

Article printed from East Asia Forum (https://www.eastasiaforum.org)

Copyright ©2024 East Asia Forum. All rights reserved.