Peer reviewed analysis from world leading experts

China’s playbook for economic success

Reading Time: 5 mins
A man works on unloading imported timber from a truck inside a timber processing industrial park in Jiujiang, Jiangxi Province, China, 16 September 2018 (Photo: Reuters/Stringer).

In Brief

China’s economic growth since 1978 has been nothing short of a miracle. Most explanations of this economic take-off have focused on what China has done right in terms of economic policy and institutional reform, rather than on the fundamental reasons for China adopting good economic policies and implementing institutional reform in the first instance.

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Share

  • A
  • A
  • A

Comparing the growth of China over the past four decades with East Asia’s other successful economies shows that China shares common elements of their success. This does not mean that market forces alone drove China’s success — the government has played a crucial role in the nation’s economic progress.

To many observers, the institutional reform launched in 1978 was the key to unlocking China’s high rates of economic growth. Price and state-owned enterprise reform and the opening up of markets were most significant. But can one say that reform has truly been the engine of growth in China? Despite many developing countries adopting similar measures — a market economy and openness to foreign investment —only a handful have succeeded in substantially raising their income.

Others argue that China has succeeded by adopting a ‘comparative advantage’ strategy. As China’s labour force was long the source of its comparative advantage, this strategy required development of labour-intensive industries. But this theory fails to explain why the market is unable to select the industries that fit with the country’s comparative advantage.

Another view is that the ‘Beijing consensus’ — typically distilled as the flexible application of neoclassical economic prescriptions — has played a decisive role. China’s government has conscientiously screened these prescriptions and their implementation has been gradual. But selective applications of neoclassical economic prescriptions are not unique to China — they are a common feature of East Asian economies.

Culture is another factor that comes to mind. A high saving rate and a relatively high level of education are key drivers of rapid economic growth. Chinese culture values both. But Chinese culture has existed since ancient times. Why did it only begin to spur economic growth after the reform?

These four views are incomplete. It is organisations and individuals that formulate policy and implement institutions. So, what factors have made the Chinese government adopt policies and institutions that favour economic growth? China’s experience offers useful lessons for other developing countries in at least the following three areas.

First, curbing patron–client politics so the government has sufficient room to pursue the interests of the entire society should be the top priority of political transformation in developing countries. Most developing countries adopt electoral politics without a social revolution, so the existing social and political structures — structures often conducive to patron–client politics — survive. The fundamental means of rooting out patron–client politics is to revamp these existing structures.

This process takes time in electoral systems. China offers useful lessons for political transformation in other developing countries, but each will have to explore the specific means by which transformation takes place.

Second, appropriate fiscal decentralisation can motivate local officials to develop the economy. Fiscal revenues in most developing countries are highly centralised with local governments frequently only controlling expenditure. In these circumstances, local officials lack incentives to develop the local economy. Granting local governments rights over revenue has been a key feature of China’s fiscal decentralisation.

Decentralisation may be even more important for resource-rich countries, where government revenues are highly dependent on the export of natural resources. These countries are constantly troubled by the ‘resource curse’. If the central government continues to control resource exports but decentralises at the same time, local governments will look for opportunities to develop other types of economic activities, putting an end to this curse.

Third, giving officials positive incentives is as important as regulating their conduct. In China, promotion is a strong positive incentive. Most developing countries operate under electoral politics, so a direct adoption of this practice is impracticable. A substitute would be to strengthen political parties’ ability to select and promote leaders. In this regard, a parliamentary system would be more advantageous than a presidential system. In countries with a parliamentary system, the public elects not just the head of government, but also that politician’s party.

The contemporary Chinese Communist Party system is both a product of the socialist revolution and a legacy of Chinese cultural traditions. It is the responsibility of contemporary Chinese policymakers and intellectuals to summarise the past few decades and construct new theory in language understood by the world. China is about to achieve its first 100-year goal — to become a well-off society. Next, it will set out to achieve its second 100-year goal — to become a modern and high income country. In between, China needs to enhance its soft power. New theories summarising what China has done right will help this, but will also contribute to the understanding of economic development globally.

Yang Yao is Cheung Kong Scholar Chair Professor and Dean, National School of Development and Director, China Center for Economic Research, Peking University.

This article is abridged from Yang Yao, ‘The political economy causes of China’s economic success’ in Ross Garnaut, Ligang Song and Cai Fang (eds.), 40 Years of Chinese Reform, China Update, ANU Press, 2018.

One response to “China’s playbook for economic success”

  1. “the market is unable to select the industries that fit with the country’s comparative advantage” said who? who else than market? weren’t markets during history doing better than state planners, which dreamed about steel production in every village? if success depends on country-wide incentives for officials: what happened to incentives when Chinese growth is slowing? why southeast provinces with many private entrepreneurs are better than northern ones?
    “So, what factors have made the Chinese government adopt policies and institutions that favour economic growth?” even after avoiding the worst starvation – caused by enlighted officials, it is wish to survive, because changing government without regular elections could be nightmare

Support Quality Analysis

Donate
The East Asia Forum office is based in Australia and EAF acknowledges the First Peoples of this land — in Canberra the Ngunnawal and Ngambri people — and recognises their continuous connection to culture, community and Country.

Article printed from East Asia Forum (https://www.eastasiaforum.org)

Copyright ©2024 East Asia Forum. All rights reserved.